If you have been paying attention to the news, you haven't escaped the recent story about an emerging contaminant being discovered in the Cape Fear River and in our drinking water.
The contaminant is known as GenX, a chemical produced by a company named Chemours and used in making Teflon for non-stick pans. Teflon is also used in nail polish, windshield wiper blades, carpet protection and clothing like Gore-Tex. Teflon used to be produced with a chemical called C8, but C8 was discovered to be toxic. GenX is the replacement product, and we don't know much about it yet. As a result, there are no standards (allowable levels) for this chemical. This is why GenX is classified by the EPA as an emerging contaminant. We don't know enough about it yet to have regulations in place.
More reading here, and here. Note that the Cape Fear Public Utility Authority has known about this for many months.
Listen to an interview with Dr. Larry Cahoon of UNCW here.
Here is a map of the area where CFPUA distributes public water from the Cape Fear (notice that our campus is right in the middle of it).
How would we analyze this issue using the tools from our course?
Could we do a cost-benefit analysis of some sort?
Perhaps a valuation study?
Thursday, June 15, 2017
Wednesday, June 7, 2017
How can we get landowners to preserve environmentally valuable lands?
We can create zoning laws that forbid certain uses of land.
Another option is to pay them to preserve.
Text below is an updated re-post:
While this progress is exemplary, the Costa Rican Minister of the Environment recently stated that it is getting increasingly difficult to conserve. Without a system of international carbon markets, such as that which might take place through large scale adoption of REDD andREDD+ schemes, he suggested that the Costa Rican path of conservation will soon be unsustainable.
Read more about Costa Rica’s PES experience here at IIED.
Read more about PES here at Ecology and Society.
Another option is to pay them to preserve.
Text below is an updated re-post:
One of the things we learn in natural resource
economics is to look at problems in terms of their costs and benefits. By
asking questions about who gains and who loses (and when, and how) we can
gain an important perspective on the causes of natural resource problems.
When given access to private benefits from
natural resources, people tend to take actions that promote their own
well-being. This access comes in the form of our daily contact with open-access
and common property resources as well as extraction and habitat conversion on
private lands. We all pollute in numerous ways to
promote our own benefits (comfort, convenience, standard of living), because it’s
cheap and easy to do so. As individuals, the costs we pay for access to the
world’s resources are low because they are shared by everyone.
How do we change the calculus? Let’s try everything and see what works. Education,
an appeal to “do the right thing”, and legal mandates on acceptable use, all
serve important roles. Monetary
incentives that affect individual costs and benefits also can be an
effective tool in many situations. These incentives come in several forms, most of
which we discuss in this course.
One incentive-based method that seems to be
gaining favor in developing nations is PES. PES stands for Payments for Environmental
Services. The basic idea of PES is to create incentives for conservation of
natural resources by transferring dollars from those that benefit from
conservation to those who bear the (opportunity) costs of conservation.
In some PES arrangements government and/or NGOs
pay landowners to engage in activities to conserve or restore biodiversity.
This can be as simple as letting a cow pasture revert back to its natural state
or setting aside lands that would otherwise be used for another purpose.
Costa Rica is a leader in PES and a great example
of the power of this approach. From the 1940s through the 1980s, Costa Rica had
one of the highest rates of deforestation in the world. As recently as 1987, forest cover in Costa
Rica was as low as 21 percent of national territory, down from over 85 percent
in the early 1900s. The principle causes of deforestation were incentives for
the conversion of land to agricultural uses, such as preferable tax treatment
for lands used to cultivate crops and support cattle, and heavier tax burdens
for “unproductive” lands (i.e. lands not used to produce market benefits). People
responded to the incentives they faced. Given the costs and benefits of land
use it made sense to convert lands to other uses.
In 1996, leaders in Costa Rica decided to try to
reverse this path of biodiversity loss. The main idea was simple: reward
landowners for conservation rather than rewarding them for land conversion. A
series of forest laws were enacted, which gave favorable tax treatment to conservation
and reforestation, banned the export of primary forest products, mandated that
banks provide low-interest loans for reforestation, created a system of
national parks and forest reserves and, in 1997, enacted a PES system.
Costa Rica’s PES system involves direct payments
to landowners in exchange for the adoption of land uses and management
techniques that provide one or more of four services: Greenhouse gas mitigation, provision of water
or other hydrological services, conservation of biodiversity or provision of
scenic beauty for recreation and tourism. Payments are provided by government. Revenues
from a fuel tax (ala Pigou) are a primary source of funding. Other sources of
funds include sale
of carbon credits to other nations and international loans. Between 1997
and 2005, a half-million hectares of forest lands were enrolled in the program.
Forest cover is now over 60 percent and rising.
While this progress is exemplary, the Costa Rican Minister of the Environment recently stated that it is getting increasingly difficult to conserve. Without a system of international carbon markets, such as that which might take place through large scale adoption of REDD andREDD+ schemes, he suggested that the Costa Rican path of conservation will soon be unsustainable.
Read more about Costa Rica’s PES experience here at IIED.
Read more about PES here at Ecology and Society.
Saturday, June 3, 2017
The economic value of the natural environment
A few weeks ago the Dean of the Cameron School of Business at UNCW, Dr. Robert Burrus, asked me to write a blog post for the Greater Wilmington Business Journal related to the economy and the environment.
Here is what I came up with.
Please let me know what you think.
Here is what I came up with.
Please let me know what you think.
Tuesday, May 30, 2017
Value and Valuation from Conservation Strategy Fund
Below are links to a great series of videos from Conservation Strategy Fund covering this week's topics:
Valuation of Ecosystem Services: Classes of Values
Valuation of Ecosystem Services: Intro to Valuation
Cost-Benefit Discounting
CSF also has short videos on each of the valuation methods.
Here is the full playlist at YouTube
Valuation of Ecosystem Services: Classes of Values
Valuation of Ecosystem Services: Intro to Valuation
Cost-Benefit Discounting
CSF also has short videos on each of the valuation methods.
Here is the full playlist at YouTube
Fees for plastic bags vs. bans
Starting on June 1, grocery stores in my home-away-from-home will charge a 15-cent fee for the use of plastic grocery bags. This initiative (basically a Pigouvian tax on an activity that generates a negative externality) has been in the works for many years and after a lot of discussion and push-back appears to be finally happening.
This particular externality has many potential solutions. A tax or fee can be imposed on the use of bags, consumers can receive a subsidy for bringing their own bags or for recycling bags, or plastic bags can be banned outright. Each of these alternatives has pros and cons.
Many areas have banned plastic bags. Examples include the state of California, the Outer Banks of NC, Austin, TX and Seattle, WA. Some places also have fees for paper bags.
Are bans on plastic bags beneficial? Maybe. Like many things that appear simple, it is a complicated issue and there are no easy answers.
Here is a short article at Scientific American on the effectiveness of bag bans.
Here is a longer article at GreenLiving noting some of the important drawbacks and unintended consequences associated with bag bans.
Here is a summary of research from the University of New Hampshire on the costs and benefits of different approaches. Importantly, the research shows that in some cases, bans might not be as good for the environment as initially thought. When lightweight plastic bags are banned, people tend to substitute thicker bags, which are worse.
This particular externality has many potential solutions. A tax or fee can be imposed on the use of bags, consumers can receive a subsidy for bringing their own bags or for recycling bags, or plastic bags can be banned outright. Each of these alternatives has pros and cons.
Many areas have banned plastic bags. Examples include the state of California, the Outer Banks of NC, Austin, TX and Seattle, WA. Some places also have fees for paper bags.
Are bans on plastic bags beneficial? Maybe. Like many things that appear simple, it is a complicated issue and there are no easy answers.
Here is a short article at Scientific American on the effectiveness of bag bans.
Here is a longer article at GreenLiving noting some of the important drawbacks and unintended consequences associated with bag bans.
Here is a summary of research from the University of New Hampshire on the costs and benefits of different approaches. Importantly, the research shows that in some cases, bans might not be as good for the environment as initially thought. When lightweight plastic bags are banned, people tend to substitute thicker bags, which are worse.
Friday, May 26, 2017
A delayed welcome - Summer 2017
Greetings class. Apologies for the delay in posting.
Now that we have several days of study under our belts, I'm curious to know what you have learned about natural resource economics. You don't have to answer all of these questions, but here are some things to consider.
For economics majors: How is the study of natural resources different than the study of market goods and services? How is the economics of natural resource use similar to the use of other goods and services?
For environmental studies majors: Has your perspective on economics changed over the past week?
What were your initial perceptions of economics and what are your perceptions now?
For all students: What does economics bring to the table in terms of understanding natural resource use and developing policy options to promote economic and environmental sustainability?
Now that we have several days of study under our belts, I'm curious to know what you have learned about natural resource economics. You don't have to answer all of these questions, but here are some things to consider.
For economics majors: How is the study of natural resources different than the study of market goods and services? How is the economics of natural resource use similar to the use of other goods and services?
For environmental studies majors: Has your perspective on economics changed over the past week?
What were your initial perceptions of economics and what are your perceptions now?
For all students: What does economics bring to the table in terms of understanding natural resource use and developing policy options to promote economic and environmental sustainability?
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)